Customer Reviews


10 Reviews
5 star:
 (5)
4 star:
 (2)
3 star:
 (1)
2 star:
 (2)
1 star:    (0)
 
 
 
 
 
Average Customer Review
Share your thoughts with other customers
Create your own review
 
 

The most helpful favourable review
The most helpful critical review


27 of 30 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars Even beter than the Bottom Billion?
I came late to the Bottom Billion and by the time I had finished it this sequel had just arrived. I got it straight away. It follows the same approach of using rigorous academic analysis and then drawing conclusions and action plans.

The analysis of elections, ethnic identity, coups and wars is stimulating and set in the context of UK, US and European...
Published on 22 April 2009 by kernel32

versus
15 of 16 people found the following review helpful
2.0 out of 5 stars Persuasive arguments, shoddily researched
I liked The Bottom Billion, but was disappointed with this - bits of it were fairly patchy, or used some proxies that don't really show what he argued they showed. I'm not a stats expert, so I won't go into detail, but I know a number of academics that really hate this book because they argue that the statistics are deeply misleading.

What I will comment on, is...
Published on 16 July 2010 by L.Gordon


Most Helpful First | Newest First

15 of 16 people found the following review helpful
2.0 out of 5 stars Persuasive arguments, shoddily researched, 16 July 2010
I liked The Bottom Billion, but was disappointed with this - bits of it were fairly patchy, or used some proxies that don't really show what he argued they showed. I'm not a stats expert, so I won't go into detail, but I know a number of academics that really hate this book because they argue that the statistics are deeply misleading.

What I will comment on, is his manipulation of the case studies to prove his point. In particular, in his case study of Cote d'Ivoire, he talked about Robert Guei leading a coup against Laurent Gbagbo in 2002, which simply isn't true. I was in Cote d'Ivoire at the time of the events in question, and it was universally known that Guei had nothing to do with the coup, which was run by a group of Northern officers and politicians. When it became clear that the coup wouldn't succeed in Abidjan, Gbagbo took the opportunity to wipe out some political opponents, including Guei and Alassane Ouattara, who narrowly escaped over the wall to the German Ambassador's house. Of course, if you accept the government line, you would believe that Guei was storming the radio station in his pyjamas, surrounded by his wife, kids and domestic staff, all of whom were killed in the firefight.

A basic google search could have turned up this information (I've just done one), but instead he chose to use a misleading case study that 'proved' his point. It just so happens that I know enough about Cote d'Ivoire to know that this was wrong, but it makes me wonder about everything else in the book that I don't know a lot about.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


11 of 12 people found the following review helpful
3.0 out of 5 stars Collier fails to impress, 24 Dec 2010
This review is from: Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places (Hardcover)
I first heard Paul Collier speak at a UK Government Economic Service conference about four or five years ago. The city was Cambridge and the subject that morning was on "economics of conflict : reducing the global incidence of civil wars". It was an energetic lecture full of empiricism and conviction. Economists and sceptics flock together, but that morning nearly every lunch table exude praise at Collier's refreshing insights on a subject that very few economists have given much thought. Since then Collier has gone on to publish the widely acclaimed "The Bottom Billion", along the way solidifying his place among the leading development experts in the world. Judging from his latest effort Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places, that wonderful enthusiasm remains undiminished.

The basic premise of Wars, Guns and Votes is straightforward: security and accountability are crucial to the economic and social development of national states. They foster economic growth and ensure more equitable distribution of wealth. More importantly, security is a "universal right" or, as Sen would put it, it is both an end and means of development. The problem is that security and accountability are fundamentally public goods whose benefits go beyond individual states and therefore failure to provide them has repercussions beyond international borders. Bringing it closer to home, failure in securing peace in the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC) is not just costly to our Congolese brothers but also to our nation and other neighbouring states through regional risk contagion, reduced intra-regional trade, increase in refugees and so forth. Like many public goods, the "free-rider" nature of security and accountability leads to inevitable under-provision.

As national states develop they tend to develop systems that internalises these "external costs" of insecurity through internal systems of accountability and external cooperation with their neighbours or to be more precise, they begin to see the benefits of sharing their sovereignty to further their long term strategic objectives. Unfortunately, for many poor African nations the process of gradual improvement towards more secure and accountable systems is impeded by significant structural weaknesses, which stem from their respective geographic sizes. Many African countries are either too large to coordinate internally (e.g. DRC) or too small to supply accountability and security that benefits everyone or put differently, the country may be too small to enjoy the benefits of security and accountability alone (e.g. Rwanda).

According to Collier, these issues matter because without recognising the structural nature of the problems, the push for democratisation is likely to amplify rather than reduce instability and political violence. Indeed, experience shows that rather than enforcing accountability and security, the African "democratic wave" has in many cases led to relapse of violence and sometimes spawned a new generation of dictators under the cloak of "democracy". Collier soberly concludes "we have most surely underestimated the degree of difficulty and promoted the wrong features of democracy: the facade rather than the essential infrastructure". This of course is not surprising because real democracy emerges from deep structural changes to the incentives of those in leadership and would-be-pretenders to the throne. The problem, argues Collier, is that these changes are difficult to come from within. Indeed even where change can be sparked, sustained security and accountability requires some form of "external intervention" or the nation state sharing some of its national sovereignty with outsiders.

Collier's proposed solution follows naturally : in order to reduce the spectre of civil wars, the international community should adopt a strategy whereby a "small intervention" from the international community can harness the political violence internal to unstable African nations. This idea of course is not new and for many who have read Collier's earlier book "The Bottom Billion", much of the book is all too familiar and simply adds more detail.

To be sure, there's a much clearer explanation of ideas in Wars, Guns and Votes than previously presented. The proposal is to establish an international standard for elections linked to a "powerful carrot". African Governments would be invited to sign-up to these internationally mandated standards. Those that do would be guaranteed "international protection" against internal aggressors (real or imaginary), who might want to take power by force. Collier assumes these to be largely disaffected military leaders who believe they can do a better (or worse) job. If the country signs up it will then be monitored, rewarded and punished on a different scale from others (no detailed exposition on the nature of these standards is provided in the book). If the leaders decided to renege on their agreement to "good governance", international protection would then be removed. Collier gets muddled here with some parts of the book suggesting that the international community might then encourage a "coup" (for example, on Zimbabwe he is forthright in noting that toppling Mugabe would have been ideal) with other parts largely silent i.e. the international community would simply remove protection and perhaps "hope" that the dissatisfied government opponents instills discipline. If the country behaved itself it would enjoy all the privileges, including some financial rewards from donors. Incidentally Collier is equally silent on whether the country that reneges first time can then come back and "play the game" again. As one thinks about the problem it becomes obvious that in so far as it's not in the interest of the international community to allow the country to remain a pariah state, it's inevitable that such a country would get another shot! This obviously weakens the credibility of the system.

More on the credibility problem later, the immediate question of course is whether African dictators (decent or otherwise) would sign-up. Collier is equivocal and demonstrates the logic through a simple "sequential game" between the country and the international community, which is solved through "backward induction". According to Collier, not only would international protection guarantees be attractive to a sitting government, but it would also be attractive to donors, which may translate in cash, allowing the reformed dictator to gain legitimacy in the eyes of his people. For their part the opposition parties would be equally amenable to seeking such an arrangement because it allows them to pre-commit to good governance, significantly enhancing their electoral appeal. As examples of where some version of the model has worked, Collier cites an old French guarantee in Francophone West Africa and the current NATO alliance. Collier's innovation is linking "security guarantees" with strong requirements on governance and electoral democracy.

That "solves" the security problem, what about accountability? Here, Collier advocates better enforcement of probity in public financing by allowing donors to impose greater "governance conditionalities" specifically with respect to budget processes. An interesting complementary proposal is for the development of new forms of budgetary processes that separates each of the government ministries into three: overall policy, allocation of money and actual supply of actions. The relevant ministry would only be responsible for overall policy and would not engage in any spending. This way it becomes easier for donors and the general public to monitor how money is being spent. Unfortunately, Collier does not discuss this idea in sufficient detail for it to deserve serious consideration by reformers. There are some musings about NGOs and charities being potential players in the actual supply of actions, but without concrete examination its difficult to judge how feasible the idea is.

Wars, Guns and Votes is certainly problematic, but not completely useless. There are valid points made throughout the book, particularly in the earlier chapters, backed by empirical force. For example, the observation that "democracy in the societies of the bottom billion has increased political violence instead of reducing it" certainly accords with my own observation that what we have in many African countries is not genuine democracy but rather electoral democracy that has not translated into genuine opening up of participation. Even in a peaceful nation such as ours and where regular elections are held, full democratisation and empowerment remains something to be hoped rather than grasped. Part of the problem is one alluded to by Acemoglu and Robinson, that is genuine democracy does not only require a shift in incentives as Collier identifies but it must be accompanied with significant shifts in power from the ruling elite to the masses. That can only occur through some redistribution of de-facto power and change in institutional arrangements (de-jure).

Collier is also right on the need for reducing aid to military spending. According Collier "on average 11 per cent of aid finds its way into military budget". Part of the problem as Collier discusses is that the move towards "country ownership" of aid through budgetary support rather than direct spend has had the unintended consequences of African governments diverting money intended for health and education towards military expenditure. This is worryingly because according to the evidence presented far from deterring violence, increased military spending especially in post conflict situations (where budget support is significantly high) provokes further violence. It appears aid financed military spending sends the signal to citizens that the political conditions may be unstable going forward which leads those opposed to government to rearm. The upshot of Collier's conclusion is that in post conflict situation better ways must be found for delivering aid e.g. through infrastructure spend and investment in human capital rather than direct budget support.

Unfortunately, as already noted there are also many areas of the book that are far from convincing. These largely fall into two camps -incomplete ideas; and, inadequate solutions. These are discussed in turn.

There are a number of instances where Wars, Guns and Votes fall significantly below the mark. I have already hinted on the muddle of the proposals and the unanswered questions related to implementation, but the problems go beyond that.

For example, the role of traditional leadership in African states in preventing corruption and violence is not fully explored. Collier dedicates a whole chapter to discussing the problem of ethnic politics and presents empirical evidence that shows that controlling for all other factors ethnic diversity is associated with greater instability and general economic retardation for the poorest nations nations. Whilst that has some empirical support , Collier's general treatment of this area is particularly lacking. For example, there's no formal discussion on the role of traditional institutions in restraining violence or perpetuating it. I remain convinced, the issue is not the absence of visionary leadership per se, but the extent to which democratic processes are fully embedded with traditional ones. African countries that have avoided civil conflicts have done so by managing these processes (e.g. Botswana whose path to tribal integration was a managed process rather than a growth driven occurrence). The issue is not the absence of visionary or charismatic leadership but development of simple and effective policies that are culturally consistent. The reason many African countries have relapsed into violence is not the absence of foreign intervention but too much promotion of foreign imposed ideas that do not recognise the unique processes that shape particular African settings.

Another example is Collier's undefended presumption of the desirability of electoral competition. Collier does not pay sufficient attention to defining the case for electoral competition. This may sound surprising, but we need to be clear on whether our goal is more electoral competition or simply deeper scrutiny. There are many countries in Africa where greater electoral competition has not translated into sustained economic growth divorced from issues related to rule of law. Conversely, some countries have little internal electoral competition but have developed checks and balances that foster growth (e.g. Botswana).

These are just two examples, which at the surface may even appear non-binding, but they hint at a fundamental problem at the heart of the Wars, Gun and Votes thesis. It does not pay sufficient attention to other forms of literature, which impacts greatly on the robustness of Collier's proposed solutions.

The golden rule is simple: if the diagnosis is partial, the solution will similarly be so, or worse generate unintended consequences. It therefore comes as no surprise that the weakest part of the Collier thesis is the proposed solution of "limited external intervention" as a mechanism to incentivise good governance. This assessment is informed by a number of observations :

a) The Collier proposal is predicated on a credible "intervention from outside". In order for any sitting dictator and the opposition to sign-up they have to believe that the relevant foreign power would be able to intervene and restore order. In practice this is unlikely. There are a number of conflicts where international guarantees would not work to prevent coups precisely because these countries are too diverse and too difficult to manage e.g. the DRC. Collier gives the British intervention in Sierra Leone as the model for intervention, but many African countries are much larger than Sierra Leone.

b) The proposal assumes unrivalled confidence and trust in western institutions. The central proposal is for the United Nations to take charge of framework for "international guarantees" and undertake the appropriate military interventions. Aside from the poor record of the United Nations in external interventions, there's a question of who punishes the United Nations if it abrogates from intervening in countries because specific sponsoring nations withdraw their support. There may well be circumstances in which the UN might not live up to its obligations and failure to which would render such charters meaningless. This is the classic problem of who polices the police. Surprisingly, Collier just glides over it without discussing how such pre-commitment problems would be resolved.

c)It suffers from a poor diagnosis of the dictatorial nature of many regimes. In Collier's simple sequential game , the threat to a sitting dictator emerges largely from a military coup or rebel insurrection. But if the Zimbabwe predicament taught us anything it is that often it is difficult to distinguish between the government and the military. The threat to Mugabe was not the military because Zimbabwe was run as junta. Collier says "Zimbabwe needed a coup" and that his system would have ensured Mugabe behaved accordingly and signed up to the governance charter. It is quite obvious to many observers that even if such a charter was presented to President Mugabe he would not have signed up because his position was ensured by the military. For Collier's incentives to work they has to be a force that threatens a sitting government sufficiently from within. In many countries such forces do not exist.

d) Collier overestimates the incentives of African government to sign-up to the voluntary charter. In Collier's model there are two things that induce government to sign-up to the voluntary charter : the protection from coups; and, the prospect of financial reward for the country. As Collier notes, but avoids deeper analysis, many nations in Africa have significant natural resources that push the incentives the other way. Why would a leader with significant oil deposits that he could sell waste time with a voluntary international charter, when they can perpetually buy-off their opponents? There's also the ever-present issue of China's role on the continent and its non-interventionist foreign policy. Again, Collier does not even mention these issues and the extent to which they may shape incentives facing African states.

I started the review by stating that Collier brings passion and expertise to the challenging issues facing developing countries. I conclude that unfortunately that is not always enough. Although Wars, Guns and Votes is steeped in empirical data it does not pay sufficient attention to the complexities of the African experience or take on board other areas of literature on the emergence and sustenance of dictatorial regimes. This has led Collier to propose, in my view, insufficient policy recommendations. That is not too say this is a wasted effort. On the contrary, Collier certainly adds rather than subtracts to the debate because the empirical evidence presented in many parts of the book provides a good platform for other economists to build on and that is no mean feat in an area that many economists have so far feared to tread.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


27 of 30 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars Even beter than the Bottom Billion?, 22 April 2009
This review is from: Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places (Hardcover)
I came late to the Bottom Billion and by the time I had finished it this sequel had just arrived. I got it straight away. It follows the same approach of using rigorous academic analysis and then drawing conclusions and action plans.

The analysis of elections, ethnic identity, coups and wars is stimulating and set in the context of UK, US and European developments, not least in that mysterious period in UK history between the end of the Romans and somewhere around 1500 - which is much like Africa today. The proposals for progress are sensible and are built around accountability and security. The penultimate chapter title is "Better dead than fed" and sums up the relationship between food (survival) and the opportunities from federations.

Readers of the Bottom Billion will be pleased to know that this book includes a full list of the countries in an appendix. Both books went to press before the "Lehman disconnect" and the onset of the latest financial and economic crisis: we must hope that the third in the series will not be called the bottom two billion. Some countries, such as Pakistan which gets a passing mention, seem determined to join Afghanistan and the five Central Asian states in the list - and none seem inclined to leave.

In truth, the book mostly concentrates on Africa - anyone wanting to know more about the likes of Bolivia, Cambodia, the Central Asian states or Haiti will not find much here other than general principles.

Professor Collier has an engaging style and as well as being stimulating it is a good read as well. He is a master of the colon: I know of no other book with as many. His occasional intemperate outbursts are a joy. This is a really good book for anyone interested in the world around them, Africa, aid, the application of academic research to real-life problems - and on many other levels too. Recommended.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


20 of 23 people found the following review helpful
4.0 out of 5 stars Evangelical democracy, 14 July 2009
By 
Peastick (Warwick, England) - See all my reviews
This review is from: Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places (Hardcover)
I've lived in Nairobi, and worked in Bosnia. So I'd seen the NGO gravy-train in all its sordid splendor, confirming my opinion that "aid is a method of transferring money from poor people in rich countries to rich people in poor countries".

At the same time I believed that we should be exporting democracy at the point of a bayonet...for everyone's sake. But it didn't seem to be working, and I didn't know why.

'Wars Guns & Votes' was recommended to me by an old Kenya hand, because it speaks about these issues - and more. Professor Collier's book explains why aid is currently likely to do as much damage as good. But he goes on to suggest plausable ways to mend the problem.

Similarly, reading this book has convinced me that we have all been kidding ourselves about the sham democracy that African elections so often disguise. Insisting that Presidents simply allow a vote achieves nothing. But linking a more accountable aid scheme with nation-building, military support and a real democracy in the way he suggests here might just bring the boat home.

I hope some big cheese reads this book, and is brave enough to take its advice to heart. But to anyone who is trying to form an opinion about Africa's political future, this book is also a must. It's sometimes a little drawn out, but on the whole Collier's self effacing style overcomes his need to produce the sort of lofty academic tome that usually flourishes in centres of higher learning.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


1 of 1 people found the following review helpful
4.0 out of 5 stars Bullets and Ballot Boxes, 27 Nov 2011
By 
F Henwood "The bookworm that turned" (London) - See all my reviews
(TOP 500 REVIEWER)    (REAL NAME)   
Political power is a fact of life. It can be wielded for good or for ill. It is much likely to serve better purposes if it can be shown that those wielding it deserve to have and it and can be trusted with it - political legitimacy, in other words. Twenty years ago, in the aftermath of communism's collapse, the answer seemed obvious. If power were taken from the ballot box rather than the bullet, this would secure peace because supposedly by definition elections are a better measure of legitimacy than armed coups.

But unfortunately, it isn't as simple as that. As Collier shows, here is no simple relationship between democracy and peace. Below a certain income level ($2,700 gross national income a year) democracies are more violent than autocracies. The societies of the bottom billion, which have experience a degree of democratisation, fall into this bracket.

What is about these societies that makes electoral competition so destabilising?

First there is strong ethnic loyalty in ethnically diverse societies. Membership of an ethnic group in a subsistence economy has strong advantages. The group will look after you when times are tough. But to ensure that this happens, you must be seen to be loyal. If there is an election, you are expected to vote for your man. These groups compete over scare resources that are allocated by oversized state sectors. Elections therefore become zero-sum games to control the source of patronage, the state. In the absence of checks and balances, governments and their opponents have every incentive to fight dirty, including resorting to violence, because the stakes are high. Once in power, the victorious group has no incentive to provide public goods like roads, railways etc. as this will benefit other groups. But ends up stunting the development of the entire country.

Elections without checks and balances, such as a culture of the rule of law and properly developed institutions to check the power of elected majorities, exacerbate violence. What we end up is an anocracy, something that is not as decisive as an autocracy but also without the accountability of an advanced democracy, a muddle of a half way house which has the worst of both worlds.

So the international community's fixation on elections to resolve the question of political legitimacy is mistaken, according to Collier. The stress should be on what works. Peacekeeping works, funding post-conflict reconstruction and basic skills like bricklaying works. Collier is interested in the nuts and bolts stuff and he is to be commended for it. Much of the analysis seems to be solidly empirical and he argues persuasively as to what the root causes of the problems of political instability and violence in the societies of the bottom billion are.

Collier moves to an analysis of how these problems might be resolved. Controversially, he argues that the problem of the provision of public goods can only be provided internationally, and not within the societies of the bottom. This means that sovereignty will have to be compromised. This of course is jealously guarded by the elites in the bottom billion. But what good does it do them? He compares Germany, which has less sovereignty on account of its EU membership than Burundi but the German economy is 3200 times the size of Burundi's.

The proposals he offers to resolve the problem of public goods provision (including military intervention) may be disputable, naïve or even unattainable but Collier wants to try and find answers and challenge lazy thinking and this he does admirably well in this book. Certainly he offers a convincing case that the logic of electoral competition in the societies of the bottom billion pretty much guarantees violence. Anyone interested in the relationship between development and conflict issues should read this book.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


4 of 8 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars Changing Reality, 29 July 2009
By 
Laurie Lee - See all my reviews
(REAL NAME)   
Verified Purchase(What is this?)
This review is from: Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places (Hardcover)
The last chapter of Collier's excellent and readable book, is called Changing Reality. And that is what really matters. Can his prescriptions for stopping wars and allowing development to take place in the world's poorest and most unstable countries be turned into reality? I believe so. Not least if enough people - including some big cheeses as suggested in another review - read it. The proposal that war and guns are one of the main causes of global poverty is not so new - though it is excellent to see it analysed as thoroughly as Collier does here. The question is what to do about it. In recent years, the answers have all been about building up the capacity to stop wars and conflicts. And the debate has been about whether the African Union could do this, or the UN? Or would it take NATO or the USA? What Collier does is refocus the debate on preventing wars, not ending them. Normally, preventing wars leads to discussions of arms control. And Collier discusses that here. But he's realistic about what can be done along porous borders, and so he looks for other ways too. His big solution is the "security guarantee": If a credible outside force says that it will intervene to stop any attempted coup, then many of the wars we have seen could be prevented. Preventing wars of course costs less lives and less money than ending them - though results in fewer medals. The question which Collier leaves us with, is whether we would be prepared for our armed forces to provide that guarantee. Given current actions in Afghanistan, that is a tough question for our society. But Collier has some tough answers as to why it really would be worth it. If you doubt it, keep your mind open and read the book.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


0 of 1 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars a must read for everyone, 7 Jun 2011
By 
Mr. N. J. Powe "nato" (uk) - See all my reviews
(REAL NAME)   
ever wondered why the world is like it is, then read this book and you will be at least a little more in touch with reality.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


2 of 5 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars Wars, Guns and Votes - Democracy in Dangerous Places by Paul Collier, 1 Sep 2009
By 
This review is from: Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places (Hardcover)
This is the book to read if you are one of those who despair at the plight of "The Bottom Billion" - the number of those of the world's population who live in abject poverty and, incidentally, the title of another of Paul Collier's books. He argues that many of the governments of countries to which the bottom billion is home are neither legitimate nor accountable, nor are they secure. Part of the problem is that people vote along tribal lines regardless of the efficiency of the incumbent government. Thus the check on poor government, supposedly provided by democracy, is impaired. Further impairment of the democratic process is caused by such nefarious techniques as bribery, intimidation and vote rigging. The reason why such techniques are employed is that the winner of an election takes all and often makes life very uncomfortable for the opposition e.g. the trashing of homes belonging to the opposition in Zimbabwe under the mendacious euphemism of "throw out rubbish". Unsurprisingly, elections under these conditions are frequently violent, the violence being exacerbated by excessive military spending, up to 40% of which is financed by donors. Worst of all is civil war which is described as development in reverse. So what is to be done? Professor Collier charts a way which lies between the laissez faire option which has left Somalia without a government for over a decade (and Al Qaida now busily trying to fill the vacuum) and the pre-emptive strike that was employed in the second invasion of Iraq. He suggests that it should be possible to harness the potent force for domestic violence for good instead of for harm and that the mechanism is the provision of minimal international intervention. This would ensure proper standards of democratic elections, and accountability and security of the elected government. In turn this would allow a raft of positive policies, described by Professor Collier, to be put in place, lifting the population out of the wretchedness that is currently their lot.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


0 of 1 people found the following review helpful
2.0 out of 5 stars too subjective, 14 Dec 2013
Verified Purchase(What is this?)
By any standards, this is not good economics. Definitions of key concepts are not given and the deductive parts of arguments are very sloppy.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


1 of 5 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars Thought Provoking, 16 April 2009
By 
C. J. SAVAGE "Footloose" (Bristol UK) - See all my reviews
(REAL NAME)   
This review is from: Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places (Hardcover)
As a frequent visitor to all parts of Africa I had observed many of the issues to which this book refers. It brought my observations into sharp relief. I found it to be a compulsive if depressing read, I found myself agreeing with many of its conclusions. If it ends up as a correct anaysis and I fear that it will be there is a good deal of heartbreak still to come in the region, but some hope as well if this book is widely read.
Help other customers find the most helpful reviews 
Was this review helpful to you? Yes No


Most Helpful First | Newest First

This product

Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places
Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places by Paul Collier (Hardcover - 5 Mar 2009)
Used & New from: £1.83
Add to wishlist See buying options
Only search this product's reviews