The Rise of the Western World and over 2 million other books are available for Amazon Kindle . Learn more


or
Sign in to turn on 1-Click ordering.
Trade in Yours
For a 2.22 Gift Card
Trade in
More Buying Choices
Have one to sell? Sell yours here
Sorry, this item is not available in
Image not available for
Colour:
Image not available

 
Start reading The Rise of the Western World on your Kindle in under a minute.

Don't have a Kindle? Get your Kindle here, or download a FREE Kindle Reading App.

The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History [Paperback]

Douglass C. North , Robert Paul Thomas
5.0 out of 5 stars  See all reviews (1 customer review)
RRP: 21.99
Price: 18.69 & FREE Delivery in the UK. Details
You Save: 3.30 (15%)
o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o
In stock.
Dispatched from and sold by Amazon. Gift-wrap available.
Want it Saturday, 19 April? Choose Express delivery at checkout. Details

Formats

Amazon Price New from Used from
Kindle Edition 16.25  
Hardcover --  
Paperback 18.69  
Unknown Binding --  
Trade In this Item for up to 2.22
Trade in The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History for an Amazon.co.uk gift card of up to 2.22, which you can then spend on millions of items across the site. Trade-in values may vary (terms apply). Learn more

Book Description

30 July 1976
First published in 1973, this is a radical interpretation, offering a unified explanation for the growth of Western Europe between 900 A. D. and 1700, providing a general theoretical framework for institutional change geared to the general reader.

Frequently Bought Together

The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History + Understanding the Process of Economic Change (The Princeton Economic History of the Western World) + Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions)
Price For All Three: 48.45

Buy the selected items together


Product details

  • Paperback: 180 pages
  • Publisher: Cambridge University Press; New Ed edition (30 July 1976)
  • Language: English
  • ISBN-10: 0521290996
  • ISBN-13: 978-0521290999
  • Product Dimensions: 6 x 9 x 0.4 cm
  • Average Customer Review: 5.0 out of 5 stars  See all reviews (1 customer review)
  • Amazon Bestsellers Rank: 407,899 in Books (See Top 100 in Books)
  • See Complete Table of Contents

More About the Authors

Discover books, learn about writers, and more.

Product Description

Book Description

First published in 1973, this is a radical interpretation, offering a unified explanation for the growth of Western Europe between 900 A. D. and 1700, providing a general theoretical framework for institutional change geared to the general reader.

Inside This Book (Learn More)
First Sentence
The affluence of Western man is a new and unique phenomenon. Read the first page
Explore More
Concordance
Browse Sample Pages
Front Cover | Copyright | Table of Contents | Excerpt | Index | Back Cover
Search inside this book:


Customer Reviews

4 star
0
3 star
0
2 star
0
1 star
0
5.0 out of 5 stars
5.0 out of 5 stars
Most Helpful Customer Reviews
13 of 17 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars First-Rate, But Not For Amateurs 30 Jun 1999
By A Customer
Format:Paperback
I read this excellent book in preparation for the writing of my senior thesis. It is the most thorough and comprehensive tretment of the economic reasons for the rise of the western world. Every sentence is information dense, and I often found it necessary to reread sentences or even whole paragraphs to digest the wealth of information and analysis. That said, it should be kept in mind that firm backgrounds in both European history and economics are necessary prerequisites for a full appreciation of this book. Moreover, this book is a crucial but nevertheless incomplete explanation for the rise of the western world. In this sense, it has everything on something (economic history), but nothing on anything else. For a broader analysis, see McNeill, "The Rise of the West." (McNeill has something on everything, but everything on nothing. Get it?)
Comment | 
Was this review helpful to you?
Most Helpful Customer Reviews on Amazon.com (beta)
Amazon.com: 3.6 out of 5 stars  8 reviews
69 of 72 people found the following review helpful
4.0 out of 5 stars A Liberal Analysis of Modernity? 15 Feb 2001
By ChairmanLuedtke - Published on Amazon.com
Format:Paperback
North and Thomas seek to explain the "rise of the Western world" by illuminating the causal importance of an efficient economic organization that guarantees a wide latitude of property rights and both incentives and protection for economic growth. Although they pay homage to both Marxian and neoliberal theory, they take a theoretical middle ground that privileges the sociopolitical backdrop of economic affairs (as opposed to solely private or class-based activity) and in doing so identifies the roots of modernization as far back as the 10th Century. To justify the novelty and originality of this approach, they write that most analysts have misidentified the symptoms of modern economic growth (technological change, human capital, economies of scale) as the causes. In doing so, previous scholars have failed to answer the question "if all that is required for economic growth is investment and innovation, why have some societies missed this desirable outcome?" (2). Their answer is that some societies (England and the Netherlands) were better than others (France and Spain) at providing an efficient economic organization that could guarantee conditions favorable to per capita economic growth among a rapidly growing population.
These conditions are conceptualized as mechanisms to reduce the gap between "social" and "private" rates of return, the key operating concepts in the analysis. Indeed, any old economic undertaking can provide private gains, but the "social" costs or benefits of this undertaking will affect the society's well-being, and a given discrepancy between the two rates of return means that a third party will absorb benefits or costs of this undertaking (an example would be the lack of intellectual property rights for inventions, leading to copying and piracy by third parties). A lack of strong property rights gives these third parties the institutional incentive or imperative to absorb social costs or benefits, and if private costs exceed private benefits then no rational chooser would ever undertake any risky new private economic activity (trade, inventions, investment, etc.). In a sense, then, the analysis becomes a refreshing neoliberal justification for strong government power.
Population growth serves as a convenient control variable for this analysis, because by holding population growth constant across all the countries concerned, the authors are able to pinpoint their causal variable (parity between private and social rates of return) in the cases where it spurred the rise of capitalism (England and the Netherlands). Population growth serves as a control because the authors show that the rise of the Western World happened only after the second population boom in the period being studied (16th Century) - the fact that it didn't happen during the first population boom (10th through 13th Centuries) means that population growth alone cannot be seen as accountable for modernity. But how did the two population booms differ from each other? Only during the second one were England and the Netherlands able to provide per capita growth by providing a climate of incentives and protections (rule of law, property rights, insurance companies, joint stock companies, etc.) that reduced the gap between private and social returns and laid the groundwork for the industrial revolution to begin.
The evidence provided to back up this causal argument comes in two primary forms: citations of historical scholarship (often quoting large passages out of encyclopedias) that are given a "new" economic spin, and a great deal of quantitative evidence, in the form of graphs and charts, to verify the cycles of population growth and economic growth and recession being identified. The authors admit that the quality of statistical data from the early period under study is rather dubious, but if one can grant the integrity of the historians that uncovered such incomplete and partial data then one can probably take this data as high-quality evidence of the trends being identified.
The authors are intentionally ambiguous about their theoretical implications. Clearly, they seek to refute Marx by showing that technological change alone could not have been the cause of capitalist development, since this change itself was a symptom of both population growth and a favorable institutional climate (what Marx would dismiss as the superstructure). However, it's not clear how much they wish to refute neoliberal theory, since they follow much of its logic regarding the role of incentives in economic growth. They admit that Adam Smith himself went too far in his laissez-faire beliefs, since a weak state would not be able to provide the kinds of efficient economic organization that our authors advocate. But their analysis does not clarify just how strong of a state is required for such organization, especially in the information age economy.
26 of 26 people found the following review helpful
4.0 out of 5 stars An Examination of Property Rights 30 Sep 2000
By Zecon - Published on Amazon.com
Format:Paperback
An outstanding book that clearly explains how `our' current understanding of property rights can be found and more fully understood through the feudal history of western Europe. The breath and sweep of this book is truly impressive. The roots of how nations protect property rights are found in western feudal history. The case is made that economic efficiency, or more specifically economic prosperity, is dependent upon how a society defines and protects property rights. Therefore, differences in economic performance among nations can be in part explained by how that particular nation's notion of property rights evolved. North and Thomas compare and contrast the development of property rights and the resulting economic performance during the feudal period in several nations, such as France and England, to make their point. Transaction costs, intellectual property, and negative and positive externalities are also discussed.
38 of 43 people found the following review helpful
5.0 out of 5 stars First-Rate, But Not For Amateurs 30 Jun 1999
By A Customer - Published on Amazon.com
Format:Paperback
I read this excellent book in preparation for the writing of my senior thesis. It is the most thorough and comprehensive tretment of the economic reasons for the rise of the western world. Every sentence is information dense, and I often found it necessary to reread sentences or even whole paragraphs to digest the wealth of information and analysis. That said, it should be kept in mind that firm backgrounds in both European history and economics are necessary prerequisites for a full appreciation of this book. Moreover, this book is a crucial but nevertheless incomplete explanation for the rise of the western world. In this sense, it has everything on something (economic history), but nothing on anything else. For a broader analysis, see McNeill, "The Rise of the West." (McNeill has something on everything, but everything on nothing. Get it?)
15 of 15 people found the following review helpful
3.0 out of 5 stars Less Than Advertised 4 Jan 2008
By R. Albin - Published on Amazon.com
Format:Paperback
This is a classic statement of the economic "institutionalist" explanation for Western dominance of the world. The North/Thomas argument is essentially that Western Europe/North America developed a set of economically efficient institutions that promoted economic producitivity growth, institutional innovation, and technological innovation. These institutions are free markets and specific forms of property rights, legal and political systems that favor market stability and security of property, and government fiscal policies that provide government with enough resources to protect market stability and property rights. Government fiscal and political policies cannot, however, undermine market forces and property rights.

North and Thomas present a concise but well done overview of European economic history from 900 - 1700 AD to support their hypothesis. The gist of their case is that a pair of nations that developed these institutions, Holland and England, developed productive and expanding economies. Those nations that did not; France, Spain, etc., either stagnated or actually declined. The development of these institutions is shown to be a contingent and essentially fortunate process. Up to this point, I think that North and Thomas make a very good case, though there may be other crucial strictly non-economic factors. Holland and England were both, for example, relatively tolerant Protestant countries.

Does this argument, however, explain The Rise of the Western World of their title? Probably not. North and Thomas have made a good argument to explain how Holland and England developed more dynamic economies than their European competitors. But does this explain the subsequent Industrial Revolution that really made possible the Western conquest of the globe? The North and Thomas story terminates at 1700, before the Industrial Revolution. Its a reasonable hypothesis that the same institutions that drove economic success in Holland and Britain contributed to the Industrial Revolution, but the most you can argue on the basis of the North/Thomas thesis is that these institutions were necessary for industrialization. They present no arguments to prove that these institutions were both necessary and sufficient to drive the Industrial Revolution.

Substantial recent scholarship like Pomeranz's The Great Divergence has argued that 18th century Qing China and 18th century Europe were economically much more similar than believed previously. Yet, the Industrial Revolution arose in Europe, not in China. To date, no one has provided a convincing explanation.
4 of 4 people found the following review helpful
4.0 out of 5 stars Rise of the Western World 15 April 2010
By Srinivas Parinandi - Published on Amazon.com
Format:Paperback
The rise of Europe to a position of unparalleled technological development and power has long been the subject of intense academic scrutiny. During the nineteenth century, anthropologists like Louis Aggasiz chalked up western dominance to biological superiority and social Darwinian theories. In the mid-twentieth century, historians replaced earlier pseudo-scientific explanations with what has become a canonical story focusing on the industrial revolution in England. In this oft-told tale, the development of new industrial technologies in England pitted new entrepreneurial classes against old aristocrats, leading to calls for greater representation as the entrepreneurs gained power. At the same time, the maturation of internal markets in England combined with surging population increases fueled a desire to search for more raw materials and new external markets. The rest of the story is predictable: England, Germany, the United States, and other countries located in the European cultural realm capitalize on massive productivity advantages and leave a huge imprint on the world that persists to the present day. This predictable story has had scores of adherents, including development economists like W.W. Rostow, who were convinced that there is a single linear path that countries can take to reach an advanced level of economic growth.

Douglass North and Robert Thomas, a pair of economic historians, disagree with the conventional story of western dominance and articulate an alternative theory in The Rise of the Western World: A New Economic History. The book is not only insightful but has also changed the game in economics: North and Thomas received the Nobel Prize in a move that many economists viewed with controversy since the book was a work of economic history rather than macroeconomic theory. North and Thomas begin their story in the Europe of the high middle ages, well before the conventional 1750s starting point of European ascendance. The decision to begin with the middle ages--a time that many other scholars believed was not worth exploring--was deliberate since North and Thomas believe that the industrial revolution has been an effect rather than a cause of western dominance. By beginning with the middle ages, North and Thomas are investigating the underlying factors that made European innovation, including the industrial revolution, possible in the first place. A set of developments occurred in certain parts of Europe at that time that allowed for the future benefits of innovation to be harvested.

At the heart of North and Thomas' argument is a simple but elegant thesis: first, "efficient economic organization is the key to growth"; and second, "the development of an efficient economic organization in Western Europe accounts for the rise of the West" (1). In the high middle ages, Europe lacked efficiency in economic structure for a number of reasons. The scale of economic interaction was low, with most transactions occurring around local manors or occasional product fairs. Also, questions about political control were patchy and unsettled at best, depriving Europe of much of the stability needed to promote economic efficiency. Finally, populations were subject to periodic Malthusian checks, the most notable being the Black Death that decimated Europe in the 1300s.

Despite these obstacles, however, kernels of change occurred in the Europe of the late medieval period and would germinate into efficiency dividends that Europe would later reap. Population declines combined with a weakening of the manorial system created a rise in the value of labor and saw the eventual replacement of feudalism with a fee based system for labor. In addition, the reappearance of a monetary economy introduced the problem of revenue generation for European monarchs since money was needed to fund activities. Some European monarchs, such as the famous example of John I of England, had to grant certain rights to landholders in exchange for resources; these rights became the forerunners to modern property rights. Other monarchs, such as those in Spain, expropriated power from nobles and embarked on a statist course of development. The contrasting fates of England and Holland, on one hand, and France and Spain, on the other, would be used by North and Thomas to illustrate the importance of facilitating efficient economic exchange.

The argument of the book reaches its peak in the 1500-1800 period. During this era, Europe's population was on the upswing and several new commercial opportunities existed due to the discovery of the New World. However, not every European country could utilize these opportunities efficiently because different institutional incentives existed in different countries. In England and Holland, which had protections for individual property including patent rights and the rule of law, entrepreneurs took advantage of hospitable regulatory climates to innovate, knowing that they would be compensated for their innovations. In France and Spain, where individual protections were far and far in between, innovations occurred at far slower rates and were accompanied by exploitative governmental policies, leading to much less efficient economic outcomes. The story of European dominance, as North and Thomas have framed it, is one of using institutional engineering to incentivize innovation. Europe's states (to varying degrees of success) found ways to protect individual effort and wealth, resulting in a leap in productivity. Technological prowess and later, world conquest, were results of efficient economic organization, not causes of it.

North and Thomas present a case that is both compelling and provocative. But the book (like all pieces of scholarship) does leave questions unanswered. One question relates to sources. North and Thomas cover a huge amount of territory--a span of almost 600 years. It is difficult to theorize about such a large chunk of time without leaving details out of the picture. Indeed, the authors address this issue directly in the book, claiming that they are trying to sketch out general precepts rather than write a history of the medieval period. To me, their justification seems reasonably convincing.

However, the statistical methodologist within me questions the general validity of their findings. The story of property rights and individual protections leading to innovations and efficient economic organization reached its fruition in England and Holland. Yet this is a sample size of 2, meaning that there are several modes of development that were not addressed here. France, for example, was a laggard to England, as were other states (not yet created during the time-span analyzed by North and Thomas) such as Germany; however, by the 1900s, these states had "caught-up" in a developmental sense and posed a threat to English dominance. In the twentieth century, Japan and South Korea stand out as two countries that pursued statist avenues of development where property rights were ill-defined to the point where governments would cherry-pick corporations to be collaborative partners. Today, property rights are better protected in these countries but both experienced huge surges in growth before the advent of better legal protections.

North and Thomas could counter my criticism with a simple reply: "we do not care about countries that followed the English/Dutch lead. Following contains certain advantages for development a la Gerschenkron. Innovations had originated in other places and were expertly adopted by these latecomers. We seek to explain how these innovations originated, not how they were adopted." This is a fair response but even it does not acknowledge an important truth: certain types of social outlooks are required to facilitate innovation in the first place. In medieval Europe, where the Catholic Church was the only institution that had truly broad-ranging power, innovation that excluded a Christian worldview was discouraged, sometimes with huge disincentives (torture and death through inquisition, for example). The Church's monopoly on power had to be broken before incentives against innovations were relaxed and breaking Church power took political will. Common historical arguments about the causes of the Protestant Reformation center on the desire of North German princes to free themselves of the Roman yoke. However, moving away from proximate causes of the Protestant Reformation and moving to ultimate causes, we may be able to borrow the North and Thomas framework to ask a new question: was the Protestant Reformation (and other changes in cultural and religious orientation) a response to shifts in economic efficiency like those described in this book? Or to put the question more broadly, what is the relationship between culture and economic efficiency? Are some places predisposed to innovation for some number of reasons? And where do politics and political systems fit in? These kinds of questions may seem politically inappropriate but they are important, particularly since inequality remains so pervasive in our world.

On balance, The Rise of the Western World is a much needed rejoinder to conventional stories of history that place the beginning of time at the start of the industrial revolution. The message of the book is fundamentally democratic: if you fix institutions and incentivize effort, efficient economic outcomes will follow. This maxim is especially empowering since it suggests that many of the world's resource poor, corruption-plagued, and strife-ridden countries could begin to get off this path by implementing some basic changes. However, building institutions that facilitate efficient economic organization is a necessary but not sufficient condition for achieving prosperity. As the Russian transition to capitalism demonstrates, the hard part comes in changing beliefs and expectations and engendering "trust" in people to believe that they will be treated honestly and fairly. Future research should focus on how to build this trust.
Were these reviews helpful?   Let us know
Search Customer Reviews
Only search this product's reviews
ARRAY(0xa6f669b4)

Customer Discussions

This product's forum
Discussion Replies Latest Post
No discussions yet

Ask questions, Share opinions, Gain insight
Start a new discussion
Topic:
First post:
Prompts for sign-in
 

Search Customer Discussions
Search all Amazon discussions
   


Look for similar items by category


Feedback